Nominal income target

Nominal income target

A nominal income target is a potential policy conducted by a central bank to target the future level[1] of economic activity in nominal terms (ie. not adjusted for inflation). The central bank could target Gross domestic product (NGDP) or Gross domestic income (GDI) numbers[2]) and use monetary policy, both conventional open market operations and unconventional tools, such as quantitative easing, to hit the target.

Contents

Mechanism

The central bank using the above tools specifies the economic activity of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period without adjusting for changes in the price level (inflation/deflation). At regular intervals, such as calendar quarters, a target level for nominal Gross Domestic Product is specified, with the levels growing at a steady rates.[3] Proponents (see Market monetarism) contend this will reduce fluctuations in economic growth, both positive and negative. In recovery from a recession, market monetarists believe excessive worry about inflation is unjustified and policy should instead focus on returning the economy to a normal growth path.

Market monetarists are skeptical of traditional monetarists' use of monetary aggregates as tools for policy instruments and prefer to use forward-looking markets as a tool to evaluate current monetary policy.[4] Market monetarists advocate for a level nominal GDP target as a monetary policy rule because it simultaneously addresses the price level and growth in an economy.[5]

Monetary policy which would ensure a NGDP expectation is met (eg. a level that reflects 5% NGDP growth from a normal trendline) by definition avoids recessions in nominal terms, and by maintaining aggregate demand also avoids deep recessions in real terms. The common target of five percent growth is often selected as it comprises three percent real growth (the historical average growth rate during the great moderation) and two percent inflation (as currently targeted by many central banks.[6] An alternative target of three percent is sometimes proposed with nominal growth mirroring the real growth rate, and hence zero inflation. This target has the potential downside of being deflationary if real growth exceeds the three percent growth in nominal terms, implying a negative rate of inflation (ie. deflation).

Because GDP and GDI figures come in after the actual economic activity has occurred, a future estimate is required; a potential option for the expected future estimate is to create an NGDP futures market and allow the market to indicate expected demand for money. The central bank would then conduct operations to move the futures price onto its target level, analogous to what it now does with the federal funds rate.

Level Target

When supply or demand shocks or policy errors push NGDP growth above or below the target, market monetarists argue that the bank should target the level rather than the rate of growth of NGDP. So if a recession pushes NGDP to 2% for one year, the bank should add the shortfall to the next year's target to return the economy to trend growth.[7]

Related policy and discussion by Central Banks

As of 2011, it is thought[8] that the Bank of England is targeting nominal income and not inflation (at least in the short term), as inflation is greater than one percent above its target, and income is growing at nearly five percent.[9]

The Federal Open Market Committee of the US Federal reserve also has discussed the possibility of a nominal income target on September 21, 2010.[10]

The Reserve Bank of New Zealand, the pioneer of inflation targetting, responded directly to a Scott Sumner report on Income targetting, stating "The Reserve Bank said that nominal GDP targeting was a complex, technical approach to monetary policy. GDP was subject to large revisions, making policy difficult to communicate."[11]

Supporters

As of Fall 2011, the number and influence of economists who supported this aproach was growing. The leading proponent was Scott Sumner, with his blog "The Money Illusion.[12] Supporters include the aforementioned Lars Christensen, with "The Market Monetarist," Marcus Nunes, with "Historinhas," David Glasner with "Uneasy Money," Josh Hendrickson, with "The Everyday Economist," David Beckworth, "Macro and Other Market Musings," and Bill Woolsey with "Monetary Freedom". Supporters of Nominal income targetting often self identify as market monetarists although market monetarism could be construed as a broader term.

References

External links


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем сделать НИР

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Income inequality metrics — The concept of inequality is distinct from that of poverty[1] and fairness. Income inequality metrics or income distribution metrics are used by social scientists to measure the distribution of income, and economic inequality among the… …   Wikipedia

  • income tax — a tax levied on incomes, esp. an annual government tax on personal incomes. [1790 1800] * * * Levy imposed by public authority on the incomes of persons or corporations within its jurisdiction. In nations with an advanced system of private… …   Universalium

  • Fixed income attribution — refers to the process of measuring returns generated by various sources of risk in a fixed income portfolio, particularly when multiple sources of return are active at the same time. For example, the risks affecting the return of a bond portfolio …   Wikipedia

  • Fixed-income attribution — refers to the process of measuring returns generated by various sources of risk in a fixed income portfolio, particularly when multiple sources of return are active at the same time. For example, the risks affecting the return of a bond portfolio …   Wikipedia

  • Market monetarism — The Market monetarism school of macroeconomics advocates that central banks target the level of nominal income instead of inflation, unemployment or other measures of economic activity, including in times of shocks such as the bursting of the… …   Wikipedia

  • money — moneyless, adj. /mun ee/, n., pl. moneys, monies, adj. n. 1. any circulating medium of exchange, including coins, paper money, and demand deposits. 2. See paper money. 3. gold, silver, or other metal in pieces of convenient form stamped by public …   Universalium

  • Quantity theory of money — In economics, the quantity theory of money is a theory emphasizing the positive relationship of overall prices or the nominal value of expenditures to the quantity of money. Origins and development of the quantity theory The quantity theory… …   Wikipedia

  • ECONOMIC AFFAIRS — THE PRE MANDATE (LATE OTTOMAN) PERIOD Geography and Borders In September 1923 a new political entity was formally recognized by the international community. Palestine, or Ereẓ Israel as Jews have continued to refer to it for 2,000 years,… …   Encyclopedia of Judaism

  • Economic Affairs — ▪ 2006 Introduction In 2005 rising U.S. deficits, tight monetary policies, and higher oil prices triggered by hurricane damage in the Gulf of Mexico were moderating influences on the world economy and on U.S. stock markets, but some other… …   Universalium

  • china — /chuy neuh/, n. 1. a translucent ceramic material, biscuit fired at a high temperature, its glaze fired at a low temperature. 2. any porcelain ware. 3. plates, cups, saucers, etc., collectively. 4. figurines made of porcelain or ceramic material …   Universalium

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”