Modigliani-Miller theorem

Modigliani-Miller theorem

The Modigliani-Miller theorem (of Franco Modigliani, Merton Miller) forms the basis for modern thinking on capital structure. The basic theorem states that, in the absence of taxes, bankruptcy costs, and asymmetric information, and in an efficient market, the value of a firm is unaffected by how that firm is financed. [MIT Sloan Lecture Notes, Finance Theory II, Dirk Jenter, 2003] It does not matter if the firm's capital is raised by issuing stock or selling debt. It does not matter what the firm's dividend policy is. Therefore, the Modigliani-Miller theorem is also often called the capital structure irrelevance principle.

Modigliani was awarded the 1985 Nobel Prize in Economics for this and other contributions.

Miller was awarded the 1990 Nobel Prize in Economics, along with Harry Markowitz and William Sharpe, for their "work in the theory of financial economics," with Miller specifically cited for "fundamental contributions to the theory of corporate finance."

Historical background

Miller and Modigliani derived the theorem and wrote their groundbreaking article when they were both professors at the Graduate School of Industrial Administration (GSIA) of Carnegie Mellon University. In contrast to most other business schools, GSIA put an emphasis on an academic approach to business questions. The story goes that Miller and Modigliani were set to teach corporate finance for business students despite the fact that they had no prior experience in corporate finance. When they read the material that existed they found it inconsistent so they sat down together to try to figure it out. The result of this was the article in the "American Economic Review" and what has later been known as the M&M theorem.

Propositions

The theorem was originally proven under the assumption of no taxes. It is made up of two propositions which can also be extended to a situation "with" taxes.

Consider two firms which are identical except for their financial structures. The first (Firm U) is unlevered: that is, it is financed by equity only. The other (Firm L) is levered: it is financed partly by equity, and partly by debt. The Modigliani-Miller theorem states that the value of the two firms is the same.

Without taxes

Proposition I: V_U = V_L ,where V_U "is the value of an unlevered firm" = price of buying a firm composed only of equity, and V_L "is the value of a levered firm" = price of buying a firm that is composed of some mix of debt and equity.

To see why this should be true, suppose an investor is considering buying one of the two firms U or L. Instead of purchasing the shares of the levered firm L, he could purchase the shares of firm U and borrow the same amount of money B that firm L does. The eventual returns to either of these investments would be the same. Therefore the price of L must be the same as the price of U minus the money borrowed B, which is the value of L's debt.

This discussion also clarifies the role of some of the theorem's assumptions. We have implicitly assumed that the investor's cost of borrowing money is the same as that of the firm, which need not be true in the presence of asymmetric information or in the absence of efficient markets.

Proposition II:

k_e =k_0+ frac{D}{E}left( {k_0 - k_d } ight)

* k_e "is the required rate of return on equity, or cost of equity."
* k_0 "is the cost of capital for an all equity firm."
* k_d "is the required rate of return on borrowings, or cost of debt."
* {D}/{E} "is the debt-to-equity ratio."

A higher debt-to-equity ratio leads to a higher required return on equity, because of the higher risk involved for equity-holders in a company with debt. The formula is derived from the theory of weighted average cost of capital.

These propositions are true assuming the following assumptions:
* no taxes exist,
* no transaction costs exist, and
* individuals and corporations borrow at the same rates.

These results might seem irrelevant (after all, none of the conditions are met in the real world), but the theorem is still taught and studied because it tells us something very important. That is, capital structure matters precisely because one or more of these assumptions are violated. It tells us where to look for determinants of optimal capital structure and how those factors might affect optimal capital structure.

With taxes

Proposition I:

:V_L =V_U + T_C D,

where

* V_L "is the value of a levered firm."
* V_U "is the value of an unlevered firm."
* T_C D "is the tax rate (T_C) x the value of debt (D)"
* the term T_C*D assumes debt is perpetual

This means that there are advantages for firms to be levered, since corporations can deduct interest payments. Therefore leverage lowers tax payments. Dividend payments are non-deductible.

Proposition II::r_E = r_0 + frac{D}{E}(r_0 - r_D)(1-T_C)

where

* r_E "is the required rate of return on equity, or cost of equity."
* r_0 "is the cost of capital for an all equity firm."
* r_D "is the required rate of return on borrowings, or cost of debt."
* {D}/{E} "is the debt-to-equity ratio."
* T_c "is the tax rate."

The same relationship as earlier described stating that the cost of equity rises with leverage, because the risk to equity rises, still holds. The formula however has implications for the difference with the WACC. Their second attempt on capital structure included taxes and identified that as the level of gearing increases by replacing equity with cheap debt the level of the WACC drops and an optimal capital structure does indeed exist at a point where debt is 100%

The following assumptions are made in the propositions with taxes:
* corporations are taxed at the rate T_C on earnings after interest,
* no transaction costs exist, and
* individuals and corporations borrow at the same rate

Miller and Modigliani published a number of follow-up papers discussing some of these issues.

The theorem was first proposed by F. Modigliani and M. Miller in 1958.

ee also


*Arbitrage pricing theory
*Capital structure
*Cost of capital
*Debt to equity ratio
*Fisher separation theorem
*John Burr Williams
*Hamada's Equation
*Pecking order theory
*Weighted average cost of capital
*Tobin's Q

Economic consequences

The Modigliani-Miller theorem, which justifies near limitless financial leverage, has largely boosted economic and financial activities.Fact|date=January 2008 But it also brought increased complexity, lack of transparency, higher risk and uncertainty in those activities.Fact|date=January 2008

Footnotes

References

*cite book |title=Principles of Corporate Finance |last=Brealey |first=Richard A. |authorlink= |coauthors=Myers, Stewart C. |year=2008 |edition=9th edition |origyear=1981 |publisher=McGraw-Hill/Irwin |location=Boston |isbn=9780073405100 |pages=
*cite book |title=The Quest for Value: The EVA management guide |last=Stewart |first=G. Bennett |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1991 |publisher=HarperBusiness |location=New York |isbn=0887304184 |pages=
*cite journal | last = Modigliani | first = F. | authorlink = | coauthors = Miller, M. | year = 1958 | month = | title = The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment | journal = American Economic Review | volume = 48 | issue = 3 | pages = 261–297 | doi = 10.2307/1809766 | url = | accessdate = | quote =
*cite journal | last = Miller | first = M. | authorlink = | coauthors = Modigliani, F. | year = 1963 | month = | title = Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction | journal = American Economic Review | volume = 53 | issue = 3 | pages = 433–443 | doi = 10.2307/1809167 | url = | accessdate = | quote =
*cite journal | last = Miles | first = J. | authorlink = | coauthors = Ezzell, J. | year = 1980 | month = | title = The weighted average cost of capital, perfect capital markets and project life: a clarification | journal = Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis | volume = 15 | issue = | pages = 719–730 | id = | url = | accessdate = | quote =| doi = 10.2307/2330405

Links

* [http://ocw.mit.edu/NR/rdonlyres/Sloan-School-of-Management/15-402Finance-Theory-IISpring2003/96178A76-03FF-426A-8AE6-5A6F014F8BF1/0/lec10awrapupfinancing.pdf MIT Sloan Lecture Notes, Finance Theory II, Dirk Jenter, 2003]
* [http://courses.essex.ac.uk/EC/EC372/ec372mm.pdf Corporate Finance: The Modigliani-Miller Theorems]
* [http://rdcohen.50megs.com/MMabstract.htm Ruben D Cohen "An Implication of the Modigliani-Miller Capital Structuring Theorems on the Relation between Equity and Debt"]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать курсовую

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Modigliani–Miller theorem — The Modigliani–Miller theorem (of Franco Modigliani, Merton Miller) forms the basis for modern thinking on capital structure. The basic theorem states that, under a certain market price process (the classical random walk), in the absence of taxes …   Wikipedia

  • Modigliani-Miller-Theorem — Die Modigliani Miller Theoreme wurden von Franco Modigliani und Merton Miller 1958 in ihrem Aufsatz The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment vorgestellt. Sie behandeln den Einfluss des Verschuldungsgrades eines… …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Modigliani-Miller-Theorem — Modigliani Mịller Theorem   [mɔdɪl jɑːni ], von F. Modigliani und M. H. Miller (1958) entwickelter Ansatz der modernen Finanzierungstheorie, wonach auf vollkommenen Kapitalmärkten unter Berücksichtigung des Risikos die Verschuldung eines… …   Universal-Lexikon

  • Modigliani-Miller-Theorem — 1. Begriff: 1958 von ⇡ Modigliani und ⇡ Miller aufgestellte Theoreme über die Zusammenhänge zwischen Marktwert, Kapitalstruktur und Kapitalkosten. Theorem I: Der Gesamtwert eines Unternehmens in einer bestimmten Risikoklasse ist bei gegebenem… …   Lexikon der Economics

  • Modigliani-Miller Theorem - M&M — A financial theory stating that the market value of a firm is determined by its earning power and the risk of its underlying assets, and is independent of the way it chooses to finance its investments or distribute dividends. Remember, a firm can …   Investment dictionary

  • Modigliani — Modigliani,   1) [ ʎaːni], Amedeo, italienischer Maler, Bildhauer, * Livorno 12. 7. 1884, ✝ Paris 25. 1. 1920; lebte seit 1906 meist in Paris und gehörte als Künstler zur französischen Schule, zur École de Paris. Er malte zunächst fauvistische… …   Universal-Lexikon

  • Modigliani, Franco — born June 18, 1918, Rome, Italy died Sept. 25, 2003, Cambridge, Mass., U.S. Italian born U.S. economist. He fled fascist Italy for the U.S. in 1939 and earned a doctorate from the New School for Social Research in 1944. He taught at several… …   Universalium

  • Miller, Merton H. — ▪ American economist in full  Merton Howard Miller  born May 16, 1923, Boston, Massachusetts, U.S. died June 3, 2000, Chicago, Illinois       American economist who, with Harry M. Markowitz (Markowitz, Harry M.) and William F. Sharpe (Sharpe,… …   Universalium

  • Miller, Merton Howard — ▪ 2001       American economist (b. May 16, 1923, Boston, Mass. d. June 3, 2000, Chicago, Ill.), pioneered the field of capital asset theory; along with Harry M. Markowitz and William F. Sharpe, Miller was awarded the Nobel Prize for Economics in …   Universalium

  • Miller — Merton Howard, 1923–2000, amerikanischer Wirtschaftswissenschaftler, der an der Business School der University of Chicago das Fach Unternehmensfinanzierung vertrat; ⇡ Nobelpreis für Wirtschaftswissenschaften 1990 (zusammen mit ⇡ Markowitz und ⇡… …   Lexikon der Economics

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”