Public choice theory

Public choice theory

Public choice in economic theory is the use of modern economic tools to study problems that are traditionally in the province of political science. (A more general term is 'political economy', an earlier name for 'economics' that evokes its practical and theoretical origins but should not be mistaken for the Marxian use of the same term.)

In particular, it studies the behavior of voters, politicians, and government officials as (mostly) self-interested agents and their interactions in the social system either as such or under alternative constitutional rules. These can be represented a number of ways, including standard constrained utility maximization, game theory, or decision theory. Public choice analysis has roots in positive analysis ("what is") but is often used for normative purposes ("what ought to be"), to identify a problem or suggest how a system could be improved by changes in constitutional rules (Tullock, 1987, pp. 1040–41). A key formulation of public choice theory is in terms of rational choice, the agent-based proportioning of scarce means to given ends. An overlapping formulation with a different focus is positive political theory. Another related field is social choice theory.

Origins and formation

The modern literature in Public Choice began with Duncan Black, who in 1948 identified the underlying concepts of what would become median voter theory. He also wrote "The Theory of Committees and Elections" in 1958. Gordon Tullock [1987, p. 1040] refers to him as the "father of public choice theory".

James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock coauthored "" (1962), considered one of the landmark works that founded the discipline of public choice theory. In particular (1962, p. v), the book is about the "political organization" of a free society. But its method, conceptual apparatus, and analytics "are derived, essentially, from the discipline that has as its subject the "economic" organization of such a society." The book focuses on positive-economic analysis as to the development of constitutional democracy but in an ethical context of consent. The consent takes the form of a compensation principle like Pareto efficiency for making a policy change and unanimity at least no opposition as a point of departure for social choice.

Kenneth Arrow's "Social Choice and Individual Values" (1951) influenced formulation of the theory. Among other important works are Anthony Downs's "An Economic Theory of Democracy" (1957) and Mancur Olson's "The Logic of Collective Action" (1965).

Public choice theory is commonly associated with George Mason University, where Tullock and Buchanan are currently faculty members. Their early work took place at the University of Virginia and Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, hence identification of a Virginia school of political economy.

Development of public choice theory accelerated with the formation of the Public Choice Society in the United States in 1965. The loci of the Society became its journal "Public Choice" and its annual meetings. The journal and meetings mainly attracted economists and political scientists. The economists brought their choice-based, model-building skill. The political scientists brought their broad knowledge of different political systems and detailed knowledge of institutions and political interaction. Scholars in related fields, such as philosophy, public administration, and sociology, also contributed.

Public choice theory is often referred to when discussing how individual political decision-making results in policy that conflicts with the overall desires of the general public. For example, many special interest and pork barrel projects are not the desire of the overall democracy. However, it makes sense for politicians to support these projects. It may benefit them psychologically as they feel powerful and important. It can also benefit them financially as it may open the door to future wealth as lobbyists (after they retire). The project may be of interest to the politician's local constituency, increasing district votes or campaign contributions. The politician pays little to no cost to gain these benefits, as they are spending public tax money. Special interest lobbyists are also behaving rationally. They can gain government favors worth millions or billions for relatively small investments. They face a risk of losing out to their competitors if they don't seek these favors. The taxpayer is also behaving rationally. The cost of defeating any one government give-away is very high, while the benefits to the individual taxpayer are very small. Each citizen pays only a few pennies or a few dollars for any given government favor, while the costs of ending that favor would be many times higher. Everyone involved has rational incentives to do exactly what they're doing, even though the desire of the general constituency is opposite. (It is notable that the political system considered here is very much that of the United States, with "pork" a main aim of individual legislators; in countries such as Britain with strong party systems the issues would differ somewhat.)

One way to organize the subject matter studied by Public Choice theorists is to begin with the foundations of the state itself. According to this procedure, the most fundamental subject is the origin of government. Although some work has been done on anarchy, autocracy, revolution, and even war, the bulk of the study in this area has concerned the fundamental problem of collectively choosing constitutional rules. This work assumes a group of individuals who aim to form a government. Then it focuses on the problem of hiring the agents required to carry out government functions agreed upon by the members.

The main questions are: (1) how to hire competent and trustworthy individuals to whom day-to-day decision-making can be delegated and (2) how to set up an effective system of oversight and sanctions for such individuals. To answer these questions it is necessary to assess the effects of creating different loci of power and decision-making within a government; to examine voting and the various means of selecting candidates and choosing winners in elections; to assess various behavioral rules that might be established to influence the behavior of elected and appointed government officials; and to evaluate alternative constitutional and legal rights that could be reserved for citizens, especially rights relating to citizen oversight and the avoidance of harm due to the coercive power of government agents.

These are difficult assessments to make. In practice, most work in the field of Public Choice has dealt with more limited issues. Extensive work has been done on different voting systems and, more generally, on how to transform what voters are assumed to want into a coherent "collective preference". Of some interest has been the discovery that a general collective preference function cannot be derived from even seemingly mild conditions. This is often called Arrow's impossibility theorem. The theorem, an economic generalization of the voting paradox, suggests that voters have no reason to expect that, short of dictatorship, even the best rules for making collective decisions will lead to the kind of consistency attributed to individual choice.

Much work has been done on the loose connection between decisions that we can imagine being made by a full contingent of citizens with zero collective decision-making costs and those made by legislators representing different voting constituencies. Of special concern has been logrolling and other negotiations carried out by legislators in exercising their law-making powers. Important factors in such legislative decisions are political parties and pressure groups. Accordingly, Public Choicers have studied these institutions extensively. The study of how legislatures make decisions and how various constitutional rules can constrain legislative decisions is a major sub-field in Public Choice.

Another major sub-field is the study of bureaucracy. The usual model depicts the top bureaucrats as being chosen by the chief executive and legislature, depending on whether the democratic system is presidential or parliamentary. (See also presidential system and parliamentary system.) The typical image of a bureau chief is a person on a fixed salary who is concerned with pleasing those who appointed him. The latter have the power to hire and fire him more or less at will. The bulk of the bureaucrats, however, are civil servants whose jobs and pay are protected by a civil service system against major changes by their appointed bureau chiefs. This image is often compared with that of a business owner whose profit varies with the success of production and sales, who aims to maximize profit, and who can hire and fire employees at will.

A field that is closely related to public choice is "rent-seeking." This field combines the study of a market economy with that of government. Thus, one might regard it as a "new political economy." Its basic thesis is that when both a market economy and government are present, government agents are a source of numerous special market privileges. Both the government agents and self-interested market participants seek these privileges in order to partake in the monopoly rent that they provide. When such privileges are granted, they reduce the efficiency of the economic system. In addition, the rent-seekers use resources that could otherwise be used to produce goods that are valued by consumers.

Rent-seeking is broader than Public Choice in that it applies to autocracies as well as democracies and, therefore, is not directly concerned with collective decision-making. However, the obvious pressures it exerts on legislators, executives, bureaucrats, and even judges are factors that Public Choicers must account for in their effort to understand and assess collective decision-making rules and institutions. Moreover, the members of a collective who are planning a government would be wise to take prospective rent-seeking into account.

Public Choice Theory has been developed largely in the context of democratic political systems of the variety that exist in Europe and North America. A pioneering work - and, perhaps, the only work to-date of its kind - seeking to analyze collective decision-making based on rules and institutions that characterize the Less Developed Countries was undertaken by Muzaffar Ali Isani at Georgetown University in 1982. It focusses largely on the assumptions of a generation of development economists who have articulated the role of the state or political action as an efficient alternative to 'economic' market failures. Isani has suggested that once we introduce 'political' market imperfections as generally found in these countries, we may be confronted with the possibility that far from correcting market failures, political action may actually prove to be a source of further distortions in the economy. He then goes on to develop an essentially economic paradigm of politics appropriate to many developing countries and which is consistent with the axioms of economic theory.

Perspective

Prior to the emergence of public choice theory, many economists tended to consider the state as an agent outside the scope of economic theory, whose actions depend on different considerations than those driving economic agents. (The many "other" economists who "did" place the state and its agents within such theory would include Vilfredo Pareto.)

Public choice theory attempts to look at governments from the perspective of the bureaucrats and politicians who compose them, and makes the assumption that they act based on Budget-maximizing model in a self-interested way for the purpose of maximizing their own economic benefits (e.g. their personal wealth). The theory aims to apply economic analysis (usually decision theory and game theory) to the political decision-making process in order to reveal certain systematic trends towards inefficient government policies. There are also Austrian variants of public choice theory (suggested by Mises, Hayek, Kirzner, Lopez, and Boettke) in which it is assumed that bureaucrats and politicians are benevolent but have access to limited information. The assumption that such benevolent political agents possess limited information for making decisions often results in conclusions similar to those generated separately by means of the rational self-interest assumptions. In another Austrian variant, developed by MacKenzie (2008a, 2008b), voters lack information on the opportunity costs of political choice, and expectation formation in politics is adaptive rather than rational. Randall Holcombe and Richard Wagner have also developed the notion of "Political Entrepreneurship".

Claims

One of the basic claims that results from public choice theory is that good government policies in a democracy are an underprovided public good, because of the rational ignorance of the voters. Each voter is faced with a tiny probability that his vote will change the result of the elections, while gathering the relevant information necessary for a well-informed voting decision requires substantial time and effort. Therefore, the rational decision for each voter is to be generally ignorant of politics and perhaps even abstain from voting. Rational choice theorists claim that this explains the gross ignorance of most citizens in modern democracies as well as low voter turnout. Rational abstention does, however, create the "paradox of voting" whereby strict costs benefit analysis implies that nobody should vote.

While good government tends to be a pure public good for the mass of voters, there may be many interest groups that have strong incentives for lobbying the government to implement specific inefficient policies that would benefit them at the expense of the general public. For example, lobbying by the sugar manufacturers might result in an inefficient subsidy for the production of sugar, either direct or by protectionist measures. The costs of such inefficient policy are dispersed over all citizens, and therefore unnoticeable to each individual. On the other hand, the benefits are shared by a small special-interest group with a strong incentive to perpetuate the policy by further lobbying. The vast majority of voters will be unaware of the effort due to rational ignorance. Therefore, theorists expect that numerous special interests will be able to successfully lobby for various inefficient policies. In public choice theory, such scenarios of inefficient government policies are referred to as "government failure" — a term akin to "market failure" from earlier theoretical welfare economics.

Another major claim is that rent seeking can waste resources. Gordon Tullock, Jagdish Bhagwati, and Anne Krueger have argued that rent seeking has caused considerable waste. In a parallel line of research Fred McChesney claims that rent extraction causes considerable waste, especially in the developing world. As the term implies, rent extraction happens when officials use threats to extort payments from private parties.

From such results it is sometimes asserted that public choice theory has an anti-state tilt. But there is ideological diversity among public choice theorists. Mancur Olson for example was an advocate of a strong state and instead opposed political interest group lobbying. More generally, James Buchanan has suggested that public choice theory be interpreted as "politics without romance," a critical approach to a pervasive earlier notion of idealized politics set against market failure. As such it is more a correction of the earlier scientific record, almost requiring a certain pragmatism in comparing alternative politicized institutional structures. [Buchanan, 2003)]

Geoffrey Brennan and Loren Lomasky claim that democratic policy is biased in favor of "expressive interests". Brennan and Lomasky differentiate between instrumental interests (dollars and cents) and expressive interests (forms of expression like applause). According to Brennan and Lomasky, the voting paradox can be resolved by differentiating between expressive and instrumental interests. While voters have virtually no instrumental incentive to vote, they do have a expressive interest in voting. Since voters vote for expressive reasons, politicians win by targeting the median expressive preferences. Bias in favor of expressive interests means that public policy often ignores important practical considerations. For example, there are instrumental costs to restricting international trade. Yet many people favor protectionism as an expression of nationalism, despite its economic costs.

More recently, some public choice scholars have claimed that politics is plagued by irrationality. Caplan's book on irrationality, "The Myth of the Rational Voter" (Princeton University Press 2007), was inspired by and is a response to the arguments put forward by economist Donald Wittman in his "The Myth of Democratic Failure". Bryan Caplan claims that politics is biased in favor of irrational beliefs. According to Caplan, democracy effectively subsidizes irrational beliefs. People who derive utility from supposedly irrational beliefs (i.e. protectionism) receive private benefits while imposing social costs. Were people to bear the full costs of their “irrational beliefs”, they would lobby for them optimally. Instead, democracy oversupplies policies based on irrational beliefs. Caplan defines rationality mainly in terms of mainstream price theory. Mainstream economists tend to oppose protectionism and government regulation more than the general population. One criticism is that many economists do not share Caplan's views on the nature of public choice. However, Caplan does have some data to support his position. Economists have, in fact, often been frustrated by public opposition to economic reasoning. As Sam Peltzman puts it "Economists know what steps would improve the efficiency of HSE [health, safety, and environmental] regulation, and they have not been bashful advocates of them. These steps includesubstituting markets in property rights, such as emission rights, for command and control. . . . The real problem lies deeper than any lack of reform proposals or failure to press them. It is our inability to understand their lack of political appeal "George Stigler's Contribution to the Economic Analysis of Regulation" 101 J. Pol. Econ. 818, 830 (October 1993).

Applications and wider recognition

Public choice's application to government regulation was developed by George Stigler (1971) and Sam Peltzman (1976). William Niskanen is generally considered the founder of Public Choice literature on the bureaucracy.

Several notable Public Choice scholars have been awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics, including James Buchanan (1986), Stigler (1982), and Gary Becker (1992). In addition, Vernon Smith (2002) was President of Public Choice Society from 1988 to 1990.

Criticism

In their 1994 book "Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory", political scientists Donald P. Green and Ian Shapiro argue that a particular form of public choice theory known as rational choice theory has contributed less to the field than its popularity suggests. [cite book|last=Friedman|first=Jeffrey|year=1996|title=The Rational Choice Controversy: Economic Models of Politics|pages=] They write::The discrepancy between the faith that practitioners place in rational choice theory and its failure to deliver empirically warrants closer inspection of rational choice theorizing as a scientific enterprise. [cite book|last=Green|first=Donald P.|coauthors=Ian Shapiro|year=1994|title=Pathologies of Rational Choice Theory|pages=6]

Linda McQuaig writes in "All You Can Eat"::The absurdity of public-choice theory is captured by Nobel Prize-winning economist Amartya Sen in the following little scenario: “Can you direct me to the railway station?” asks the stranger. “Certainly,” says the local, pointing in the opposite direction, towards the post office, “and would you post this letter for me on your way?” “Certainly,” says the stranger, resolving to open it to see if it contains anything worth stealing."

(Sen, in fact, has participated in the development of public choice theory, in such works as "Collective Choice and Social Welfare".)

Public Choice theorists have been criticized for failure to explain human actions motivated by non-rational or non-economic considerations. They respond, however, that the theory explains a broad variety of actions since humanitarian or even a madman's actions are also rational. This way, the argument goes, public choice allows to account for a much broader variety of actions than any other approach, and in the example above, Sen's rational actors may or may not act in a way he identified, since public choice approach does not mean the actors necessarily take advantage of one another; it only implies that the actions are 'rational'. Action to direct someone to a train station would thus be just as rational as the action to direct the stranger away for one's own reasons. Furthermore, only 'rationalism' helps to explain human motivation, whereas any other approaches such as humanitarian considerations or the willingness to get extra profit (which is in no way the same as 'rational action') would only explain a part of the developments and fails to present a comprehensive picture. Also, Bryan Caplan argues against rationality in politics, and Brennan and Lomasky account for expressive (non-economic) motives in politics.

Schram and Caterino (2006) contains a fundamental methodological criticism of public choice theory for promoting the view that the natural science model is the only appropriate methodology in social science and that political science should follow this model, with its emphasis on quantification and mathematization. Schram and Caterino argue instead for methodological pluralism.

ee also

*Choice Modelling
*Subsidiarity
*Regulatory Capture

Notes

References

Most public choice articles in the JEL classification codes fall under JEL D72 (Economic Models of Political Processes: Rent-Seeking, Elections, Legislatures, and Voting Behavior).

*Arrow, Kenneth J. (1951, 2nd ed., 1963), "Social Choice and Individual Values"
*Black, Duncan (1958), "The Theory of Committees and Elections". Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
*Buchanan, James M. (2003). [http://www.gmu.edu/centers/publicchoice/pdf%20links/Booklet.pdf "Public Choice: The Origins and Development of a Research Program,"] Fairfax, Va.: Center for Study of Public Choice, George Mason University.
*Buchanan, James M. and Gordon Tullock. (1962), "The Calculus of Consent". Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.
*Downs, Anthony. (1957), "An Economic Theory of Democracy". Cambridge: York: Cambridge University Press.
*Isani, Muzaffar Ali. (1982), "An Economic Approach to Politics in Developing Countries". Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Georgetown University, Washington, D.C.
*MacKenzie, DW. (2008), "The Use of Knowledge about Society". Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization.
*MacKenzie, DW. (2008), "Politics and Knowledge: Expectations formation in Democracy". Working paper, Presented at the Southern Economics Association Conference in 2005.
*Mueller, Dennis C. (1989), "Public Choice II". Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
*Niskanen, W. A. (1987) “Bureaucracy." In Charles K. Rowley (Ed. ). "Democracy and Public Choice". Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
*Olson, Mancur, Jr. (1965) "The Logic of Collective Action". Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
*Ostrom, Vincent (1986), "The Theory of the Compound Republic". Lincoln, Nebraska: University of Nebraska Press. Second edition.
*Riker, William H. (1962), "The Theory of Political Coalitions". New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
* [http://books.google.com/books?id=kyJ5GJ7DeMQC&printsec=frontcover&dq=%22Making+Political+Science+Matter%22&sig=s_bqA18zhy02NKJwsJHJj3vHzKc Schram, Sanford F. and Brian Caterino (2006eds.). "Making Political Science Matter: Debating Knowledge, Research, and Method". New York and London: New York University Press.]
*Tullock, Gordon (1987), "public choice" in "The ", v. 3, pp. 1040–44.
* _____ (1989), "The Economics of Special Privilege and Rent-Seeking". Boston & Dordrecht, Netherlands: Kluwer Academic Publishers.

External links

* [http://ssrn.com/abstract=1103644 A Comparative Bibliography: Regulatory Competition on Corporate Law]
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Buchanan/buchCContents.html "Collected Works of James M. Buchanan"] at the Library of Economics and Liberty.
* [http://www.rent-seeking.net"Many Papers on Public Choice and Rent-seeking"] By Behrooz Hassani-M
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Buchanan/buchCv3Contents.html "The Calculus of Consent"] by James M. Buchanan and Gordon Tullock
* [http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/PublicChoiceTheory.html "Public Choice Theory"] at the "Concise Encyclopedia of Economics"
* [http://www.gmu.edu/departments/economics/bcaplan/e410/econ410.htm Notes for a course in public choice] by Bryan Caplan
* [http://perspicuity.net/sd/pub-choice.html Introduction to Public Choice Theory] by Leon Felkins. Contains numerous links of interest
* [http://www.nomadpress.com/public_choice/34432.html The Field of Public Choice] by Pat Gunning
* [http://www.pubchoicesoc.org/about2.htm "Statement of Purpose,"] Public Choice Society
* [http://www.canaktan.org/ekonomi/anayasal_iktisat/anasayfa-anayasaliktisat.htm Turkish Public Choice Site]
* [http://unjobs.org/tags/public-choice-theory Public choice documents on unjobs.org]


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем написать курсовую

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Public Choice Theory — Die Neue Politische Ökonomie (NPÖ) (auch Public Choice), umfasst jene Theorien und Forschungsgebiete, die politisches Verhalten, Entscheidungsprozesse und Strukturen überwiegend auf Basis der neoklassischen Wirtschaftstheorie erklären. Betrachtet …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Rational choice theory — This article is about a theory of economics. For Rational Choice Theory as applied to criminology, see Rational choice theory (criminology). Economics …   Wikipedia

  • Social choice theory — is a theoretical framework for measuring individual interests, values, or welfares as an aggregate towards collective decision. A non theoretical example of a collective decision is passing a set of laws under a constitution. Social choice theory …   Wikipedia

  • Rational Choice Theory — Theorie der rationalen Entscheidung oder Rational choice theory [ ræʃənl tʃɔɪs] ist eine Sammelbezeichnung für verschiedene Ansätze einer Handlungstheorie der Wirtschafts und Sozialwissenschaften. Generell schreiben diese Ansätze handelnden… …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Social Choice Theory — Die Sozialwahltheorie (engl. Social Choice Theory), auch Theorie kollektiver Entscheidungen (engl. Theory of Collective Choice) genannt, beschäftigt sich mit Gruppenentscheidungen durch Aggregation von individuellen Präferenzen/Entscheidungen zu… …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Public sector economics — (or public economics for short) is the study of economic issues that concern the public sector in a mixed economy. While much of economics is based on how markets work, public sector economics focuses on why markets fail, and what issues arise… …   Wikipedia

  • Choice architecture — describes the way in which decisions are influenced by how the choices are presented (in order to influence the outcome), and is a term used by Cass Sunstein and economist Richard Thaler in the 2008 book Nudge: Improving Decisions about Health,… …   Wikipedia

  • Public reason — is the phrase used by American philosopher John Rawls to refer to the common reason of all citizens in a pluralist society. External links * [http://www2.warwick.ac.uk/fac/soc/philosophy/staff/peter/peter pr.pdf Fabienne Peter: Rawls’ Idea of… …   Wikipedia

  • Journal of Public Economic Theory — The Journal of Public Economic Theory ( JPET ) is a journal of public economics published by Blackwell. [ [http://www.blackwellpublishing.com/journal.asp?ref=1097 3923 site=1 Blackwell] ] Apart from public economic theory and general economics,… …   Wikipedia

  • Public good — For the egalitarian terms, see Common good and Public interest. In economics, a public good is a good that is nonrival and non excludable. Non rivalry means that consumption of the good by one individual does not reduce availability of the good… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”