Kaldor-Hicks efficiency

Kaldor-Hicks efficiency

Kaldor-Hicks efficiency (named for Nicholas Kaldor and John Hicks) is a measure of economic efficiency that captures some of the intuitive appeal of Pareto efficiency, but has less stringent criteria and is hence applicable to more circumstances. Under Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, an outcome is considered more efficient if a Pareto optimal outcome can be reached by arranging some compensation from those that are made better off to those that are made worse off.

Explanation

Under Pareto efficiency, an outcome is more efficient if at least one person is made better off and nobody is made worse off. This seems a reasonable way to determine whether or not an outcome improves economics efficiency. However, some believe that in practice, it is almost impossible to take any social action, such as a change in economic policy, without making at least one person worse off. Even voluntary exchanges may not be Pareto improving. Under ideal conditions, voluntary exchanges are Pareto improving since individuals would not enter into them unless they were mutually beneficial. However, a voluntary exchange would not be Pareto superior if external costs (such as pollution that hurt a third party) exist, as they often do.

Using Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, an outcome is more efficient if those that are made better off could "in theory" compensate those that are made worse off, so that a Pareto improving outcome results. For example, a voluntary exchange that creates pollution would be a "Kaldor-Hicks improvement" if the buyers and sellers are still willing to carry out the transaction even if they have to fully compensate the victims of the pollution.

The key difference is the question of compensation. Kaldor-Hicks does not require compensation actually be paid, merely that the possibility for compensation exists, and thus does not necessarily make each party better off (or neutral). Thus, under Kaldor-Hicks efficiency, a more efficient outcome can in fact leave some people worse off. Pareto efficiency requires making every party involved better off (or at least no worse off).

While every Pareto improvement is a Kaldor-Hicks improvement, most Kaldor-Hicks improvements are not Pareto improvements. This is because, as the graph above illustrates, the set of Pareto improvements is a subset of Kaldor-Hicks improvement, which also reflects the greater flexibility and applicability of the Kaldor-Hicks criteria relative to the Pareto criteria. For example, in a society with two people, suppose initially Person A has 10 sheep and Person B has 100 sheep. If some policy change or other shock results with Person A ending up with 20 sheep and Person B with 99 sheep, this change would not be Pareto improving, since Person B is now worse off. However, it would be a Kaldor-Hicks improvement, as Person A could theoretically give Person B anywhere between 1 and 10 sheep to accept this alternative situation.

Use in policy making

The Kaldor-Hicks methods are typically used as tests of Pareto efficiency rather than as efficiency goals themselves. They are used to determine whether an activity is moving the economy towards Pareto efficiency. Any change usually makes some people better off while making others worse off, so these tests ask what would happen if the winners were to compensate the losers.

Using the "Kaldor criterion" an activity will contribute to Pareto optimality if the maximum amount the gainers are prepared to pay is greater than the minimum amount that the losers are prepared to accept.

Under the "Hicks criterion", an activity will contribute to Pareto optimality if the maximum amount the losers are prepared to offer to the gainers in order to prevent the change is less than the minimum amount the gainers are prepared to accept as a bribe to forgo the change. The Hicks compensation test is from the losers' point of view, while the Kaldor compensation test is from the gainers' point of view. After several technical problems with each separate criterion were discovered, they were combined into the Scitovsky criterion, more commonly known as the "Kaldor-Hicks criterion", which does not share the same flaws.

The Kaldor-Hicks criterion is widely applied in welfare economics and managerial economics. For example, it forms an underlying rationale for cost-benefit analysis. In cost-benefit analysis, a project (for example, a new airport) is evaluated by comparing the total costs, such as building costs and environmental costs, with the total benefits, such as airline profits and convenience for travelers. (However, as cost-benefit analysis may also assign different social welfare weights to different individuals, e.g. more to the poor, the compensation criterion is not always invoked by cost-benefit analysis.)

The project would typically be given the go-ahead if the benefits exceed the costs. This is effectively an application of the Kaldor-Hicks criterion, because it is equivalent to requiring that the benefits should be enough that those that benefit could in theory compensate those that have lost out. The criterion is used because it is argued that it is justifiable for society as a whole to make some worse off if this means a greater gain for others.

Criticisms

The most common criticism of the Kaldor-Hicks criterion is that it only takes into account the absolute level of income, but disregards its distribution.

A related problem is that any social welfare functions based on Kaldor-Hicks criteria are cardinal in nature, and therefore suffer from the aggregation problems associated with discrepancies between the marginal value of money of rich and poor people.

This has mainly to do with the assumption of diminishing marginal utility for income: taking one dollar from a poor person causes a greater loss in utility than taking a dollar from a rich one. By weighting utility variations by the marginal utilities, the social welfare function implicit to the Kaldor-Hicks compensation principle is represented by anti-egalitarian, concave indifference curves.

At a more technical level, various versions of the Kaldor-Hicks criteria lack desirable formal properties. For instance, Tibor Scitovsky demonstrated that the Kaldor criterion alone is not symmetric: it's possible to have a situation where an outcome A is an improvement (according to the Kaldor criterion) over outcome B, but B is also an improvement over A. The combined Kaldor-Hicks criterion does not have this problem, but it can be non-transitive (A may be an improvement over B, and B over C, but A may not be an improvement over C). [cite journal |last=Scitovsky |first=Tibor |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1941 |month= |title=A Note on Welfare Propositions in Economics |journal=Review of Economic Studies |volume=9 |issue=1 |pages=77–88 |doi=10.2307/2967640 |url= |accessdate= |quote= ] [cite web |url=http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/paretian/paretosocial.htm#scitovsky |title=The Paretian System: Scitovsky Reversals and the Double Criteria |accessdate= |last=Fonseca |first=Gonçalo L. |work= |publisher= |date= ]

ee also

*Compensation principle
*Welfare economics
*Pareto efficiency

References

Further reading

*cite journal |last=Hicks |first=John |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1939 |month= |title=The Foundations of Welfare Economics |journal=Economic Journal |volume=49 |issue=196 |pages=696–712 |doi=10.2307/2225023 |url= |accessdate= |quote=
*cite journal |last=Kaldor |first=Nicholas |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1939 |month= |title=Welfare Propositions in Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility |journal=Economic Journal |volume=49 |issue=195 |pages=549–552 |id= |url= |accessdate= |quote=
*cite book |title=Economic Analysis of Law |last=Posner |first=Richard A. |authorlink= |edition=Seventh Edition |year=2007 |publisher=Wolters Kluwer |location=Austin, TX |isbn=0735563543 |pages=


Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Поможем решить контрольную работу

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Hicks — may refer to:People with the surname Hicks: *Hicks (surname)Other: * Hick, a derogatory Americanism (term) for a person from a rural area * Kaldor Hicks efficiency, a type of economic efficiency * HM Capital, a private US equity firm, formerly… …   Wikipedia

  • Efficiency — as a technical term may refer to: * Algorithmic efficiency, optimizing the speed and memory requirements of a computer program * Efficient energy use, useful work per quantity of energy ** Energy conversion efficiency, desired energy output per… …   Wikipedia

  • Nicholas Kaldor — Post Keynesian economics Born 12 May 1908(1908 05 12) Budapest, Hungary Died …   Wikipedia

  • Pareto efficiency — Pareto efficiency, or Pareto optimality, is an important concept in economics with broad applications in game theory, engineering and the social sciences. The term is named after Vilfredo Pareto, an Italian economist who used the concept in his… …   Wikipedia

  • John Hicks — Infobox Scientist name = John R. Hicks image size = 180px birth date = birth date|1904|4|8|mf=y birth place = Warwick, England death date = death date and age|1989|5|20|1904|4|8|mf=y death place = New York City, New York nationality = United… …   Wikipedia

  • Dynamic efficiency — is a term in economics, which refers to an economy that appropriately balances short run concerns (static efficiency) with concerns in the long run (focusing on encouraging research and development).[1] Through dynamic efficiency, such an economy …   Wikipedia

  • Economic efficiency — is used to refer to a number of related concepts. A system can be called economically efficient if: * No one can be made better off without making someone else worse off. * More output cannot be obtained without increasing the amount of inputs. * …   Wikipedia

  • Allocative efficiency — is a theoretical measure of the benefit or utility derived from a proposed or actual selection in the allocation or allotment of resources.[1][2] Although there are different standards of evaluation for the concept of allocative efficiency, the… …   Wikipedia

  • Welfare economics — Economics …   Wikipedia

  • Law and economics — Law and Economics, or economic analysis of law is an approach to legal theory that applies methods of economics to law. It includes the use of economic concepts to explain the effects of laws, to assess which legal rules are economically… …   Wikipedia

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”