Coase conjecture

Coase conjecture

The Coase conjecture, developed first by Ronald Coase, is an argument in monopoly theory. The conjecture sets up a situation in which a monopolist sells a durable good to a market where resale is impossible and faces consumers who all have different valuations. The conjecture proposes that a monopolist that does not know individuals' valuations will have to sell its product at a low price if the monopolist tries to separate consumers by offering different prices in different periods. This is because the monopoly is, in effect, in price competition with itself over several periods and the consumer with the highest valuation, if he is patient enough, can simply wait for the lowest price. Thus the monopolist will have to offer a competitive price in the first period which will be low. The monopolist could avoid this problem by committing to a stable linear pricing strategy or adopting other business strategies [1].

Contents

Simple two-consumer model

Imagine there are consumers, called X and Y with valuations of good with x and y respectively. The valuations are such as x < y < 2x. The monopoly cannot directly identify individual consumers but it knows that there are 2 different valuations of a good. The good being sold is durable so that once a consumer buys it, he or she will still have it in all subsequent periods. This means that after the monopolist has sold to all consumers, there can be no further sales. Also assume that production is such that average cost and marginal cost are both equal to zero.

The monopolist could try to charge at a price = y in the first period and then in the second period price = x, hence price discriminating. This will not result in consumer Y buying in the first period because, by waiting, she could get price equal to x. To make consumer Y indifferent between buying in the first period or the second period, the monopolist will have to charge a price of price = dx + (1 − d)y where d is a discount factor between 0 and 1. This price is such as dx + (1 − d)y < y.

Hence by waiting, Y forces the monopolist to compete on price with its future self.

n consumers

Imagine there are n consumers with valuations ranging from y to a valuation just above zero. The monopoly will want to sell to the consumer with the lowest valuation. This is because production is costless and by charging a price just above zero it still makes a profit. Hence to separate the consumers, the monopoly will charge first consumer (1 − dn)y where n is the number of consumers. If the discount factor is high enough this price will be close to zero. Hence the conjecture is proved.

See also

References

  1. ^ http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=496175 [Orbach (2004)

Further reading

  1. Coase, Ronald. "Durability and Monopoly" in Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 15(1), pp. 143–49, 1972.
  2. Orbach, Barak. "The Durapolist Puzzle: Monopoly Power in Durable-Goods Market" in Yale Journal on Regulation, vol. 21(1), pp. 67–118, 2004.

Wikimedia Foundation. 2010.

Игры ⚽ Нужно сделать НИР?

Look at other dictionaries:

  • Coase-Vermutung — Die Coase Vermutung (Coase Conjecture) beschreibt das Preissetzungsverhalten eines Monopols, welches langlebige Wirtschaftsgüter herstellt. Ronald Coase vermutete, dass sich im Grenzfall ein solches Monopol wie ein Unternehmen bei vollständigem… …   Deutsch Wikipedia

  • Ronald Coase — New institutional economics Born 29 December 1910 (1910 12 29) (age 100) …   Wikipedia

  • Pacman conjecture — The Pacman Conjecture holds that durable goods monopolists have complete market power and so can exercise perfect price discrimination thus extracting the total surplus [Coase versus Pacman: Who Eats Whom in the Durable Goods Monopoly?Author(s):… …   Wikipedia

  • List of economics topics — This aims to be a complete list of the articles on economics. It does not include articles about economists, who are listed in the list of economists. NOTOC A * Accounting Accounting reform Actuary Adaptive expectations Adverse selection Agent… …   Wikipedia

  • Durable good — A car is a durable good. The gasoline that powers it is a non durable good. In economics, a durable good or a hard good is a good that does not quickly wear out, or more specifically, one that yields utility over time rather than being completely …   Wikipedia

  • Scientific phenomena named after people — This is a list of scientific phenomena and concepts named after people (eponymous phenomena). For other lists of eponyms, see eponym. NOTOC A* Abderhalden ninhydrin reaction Emil Abderhalden * Abney effect, Abney s law of additivity William de… …   Wikipedia

  • List of mathematics articles (C) — NOTOC C C closed subgroup C minimal theory C normal subgroup C number C semiring C space C symmetry C* algebra C0 semigroup CA group Cabal (set theory) Cabibbo Kobayashi Maskawa matrix Cabinet projection Cable knot Cabri Geometry Cabtaxi number… …   Wikipedia

  • List of philosophy topics (A-C) — 110th century philosophy 11th century philosophy 12th century philosophy 13th century philosophy 14th century philosophy 15th century philosophy 16th century philosophy 17th century philosophy 18th century philosophy 19th century philosophy220th… …   Wikipedia

  • Liste de théorèmes — par ordre alphabétique. Pour l établissement de l ordre alphabétique, il a été convenu ce qui suit : Si le nom du théorème comprend des noms de mathématiciens ou de physiciens, on se base sur le premier nom propre cité. Si le nom du théorème …   Wikipédia en Français

Share the article and excerpts

Direct link
Do a right-click on the link above
and select “Copy Link”